For years RBA assistant governor, Luci Ellis, has tried to argue that part of the reason why Australian housing is so expensive is because it is far more urbanised than other comparable economies.
Part of the perception of supply constraints comes from our view of Australia as a big country. Yes, we have a lot of land. What we don’t have much of is land where people actually want to live. In general, desirable land is the land within or adjacent to existing settlements. Australia’s population is heavily urbanised compared with other developed countries, let alone most emerging countries.
It is also quite concentrated in a couple of large cities (Graph 6). So the range of acceptable locations is actually more limited than the map would lead you to believe.
And in last week’s speech, Ellis made a similar argument in trying to explain the gaping dwelling price difference between Australia and the United States:
Advertisement
What we can do is get some sense of the relativities between countries that you might expect, given those institutional and other differences. For example, we can reasonably expect that countries where much of the population lives in smaller, cheaper cities will have lower national aggregate ratios of housing prices to incomes than other countries. That might partly explain why the price-to-income ratio for the United States is relatively low.
Last year, Gareth Brown at the Bristlemouth Blogshowed comprehensively that that the RBA had juked the stats on urbanisation rates by wrongly comparing the greater metropolitan areas of Australia’s cities against only the central inner city areas of other nations. This is why Australia’s urbanisation rate is around 75% versus just under 30% in the United States (see above chart).
Leith van Onselen is Chief Economist at the MB Fund and MB Super. He is also a co-founder of MacroBusiness.
Leith has previously worked at the Australian Treasury, Victorian Treasury and Goldman Sachs.